Advertisement

“One Man, One Vote” Part 1: Electoral Justice in the U.S. Electoral College: Banzhaf and Shapley/Shubik Versus May

Chapter
Part of the Studies in Choice and Welfare book series (WELFARE)

Abstract

This paper is dedicated to the measurement of (or lack of) electoral justice in the 2010 Electoral College using a methodology based on the expected influence of the vote of each citizen for three probability models. Our first contribution is to revisit and reproduce the results obtained by Owen (1975) for the 1960 and 1970 Electoral College. His work displays an intriguing coincidence between the conclusions drawn, respectively, from the Banzhaf and Shapley-Shubik’s probability models. Both probability models conclude to a violation of electoral justice at the expense of small states. Our second contribution is to demonstrate that this conclusion is completely flipped upside down when we use May’s probability model: This model leads instead to a violation of electoral justice at the expense of large states. Besides unifying disparate approaches through a common measurement methodology, one main lesson of the paper is that the conclusions are sensitive to the probability models which are used and in particular to the type and magnitude of correlation between voters that they carry.

Notes

Acknowledgements

We are very pleased to offer this paper as a contribution to this volume honoring Bill Gehrlein and Dominique Lepelley with whom we had the pleasure to cooperate in the recent years. Both have made important contributions to the evaluation of voting rules and electoral systems through probability models. Power measurement and two-tier electoral systems, the two topics of our paper, are parts of their general research agenda. We hope that they will find our paper respectful of the approach that they have been promoting in their work. Last, but not least, we would like to thank two anonymous referees who have attracted our attention on the imperfections and shortcomings contained in an earlier version and whose comments and suggestions have improved a lot the exposition of the ideas developed in our paper. Of course, they should not be held responsible for any of the remaining insufficiencies. The working paper version, available on the Web sites of the authors, contains three appendices offering supplementary mathematical developments on the intricacies of the Shapley-Shubik’s probability model and its discrete counterpart. The three first authors acknowledge funding from the French National Research Agency (ANR) under the Investments for the Future program (Investissements d’ Avenir, grant ANR-17 EURE-0010).

References

  1. Balinski ML (2005) What is just? Am Math Monthly 112:502–511CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Banzhaf JF (1964) Weighted voting doesn’t work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers L Rev 19(2):317–343Google Scholar
  3. Beloff M (1952) Les sièges universitaires. Rev Fran Sci Po 2:295–302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Chamberlain G, Rothschild M (1981) A note on the probability of casting a decisive vote. J Econ Theory 25:152–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. De Mouzon O, Laurent T, Le Breton M, Lepelley D (2019) Exploring the effects on the Electoral College of national and regional popular vote interstate compact: an electoral engineering perspective. Public Choice 179:51–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. De Mouzon O, Laurent T, Le Breton M (2020a) “One man, one vote” part 2: apportionment, measurement of disproportionality and the Lorenz curve. MimeoGoogle Scholar
  7. De Mouzon O, Laurent T, Le Breton M, Lepelley D (2020b) The theoretical Shapley-Shubik probability of an election inversion in a toy symmetric version of the U.S. presidential electoral system. Soc Choice Welfare (Forthcoming)Google Scholar
  8. Droz J (1963) L’origine de la loi des trois classes en Prusse. Rev Histo XIXe siècle 1848 22:1–45Google Scholar
  9. Durran DR (2017) Whose votes count the least in the Electoral College? https://theconversationcomGoogle Scholar
  10. Felsenthal DS, Machover M (1998) The measurement of voting power: theory and practice, problems and paradoxes. Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
  11. Gelman A, King G, Boscardin WJ (1998) Estimating the probability of events that have never occured: when is your vote decisive? J Am Stat Assoc 93:1–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Gelman A, Katz JN, Tuerlinckx F (2002b) The mathematics and statistics of voting power. Stat Sci 17:420–435CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Gelman A, Katz JN, Bafumi J (2004) Standard voting power indexes do not work: an empirical analysis. Br J Polit Sci 34:657–674CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Gelman A, Silver N, Edlin A (2012) What is the probability your vote will make a difference? Econ Inq 50(2):321–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Gelman A, Katz JN, King G (2002a) Empirically evaluating the Electoral College. In: Crigler AN, Just MR, McCaffery EJ (eds) Rethinking the vote: the politics and prospects of American election reform. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  16. Good IJ, Mayer LS (1975) Estimating the efficacy of a vote. Behav Sci 20:25–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Hayes B (2012) College ties. Bit player. http://bit-playerorg/publications-by-brian-hayesGoogle Scholar
  18. Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2011) Voting and collective decision-making: bargaining and power. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  19. Le Breton M, Lepelley D (2014) Une analyse de la loi électorale du 29 juin 1820. Rev Éco 65:469–518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Le Breton M, Van Der Straeten K (2015) Influence versus utility in the evaluation of voting rules: a new look at the Penrose formula. Public Choice 165:103–122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Le Breton M, Lepelley D, Smaoui H (2016) Correlation, partitioning and the probability of casting a decisive vote under the majority rule. J Math Econ 64:11–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Le Breton M, Lepelley D, Merlin V, Sauger N (2017) Le scrutin binominal paritaire : un regard d’ingénierie électorale. Revue Éco 68:965–1004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Margolis H (1983) The Banzhaf fallacy. Am J Polit Sci 27:321–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. May K (1948) Probability of certain election results. Amer Math Monthly 55:203–209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Miller NR (2009) A priori voting power and the U.S. Electoral College. Homo Oeconomicus 26:341–380Google Scholar
  26. Miller NR (2012) Why the Electoral College is good for political science (and public choice). Public Choice 150:1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Mulligan CB, Hunter CG (2003) The empirical frequency of a pivotal vote. Public Choice 116:31–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Newman EL (1974) The blouse and the frock coat: the alliance of the common people of Paris with the liberal leadership and the middle class during the last years of the Bourbon restoration. J Mod History 46:26–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Owen G (1975) Evaluation of a presidential election game. Am Polit Sci Rev 69:947–953CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Owen G (2001) Game theory, 3rd edn. Academic Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  31. Penrose LS (1946) The elementary statistics of majority voting. J R Stat Soc 109:53–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Penrose LS (1952) On the objective study of crowd behaviour. HK Lewis and Co, LondonGoogle Scholar
  33. Schilfert G (1963) L’application de la loi des trois classes en Prusse. In: Bibliothèque de la Révolution de 1848, Tome 22, Réaction et suffrage universel en France et en Allemagne (1848–1850)Google Scholar
  34. Shapley LS (1962) Simple games: an outline of the descriptive theory. Behav Sci 7:59–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48:787–792CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Shugart MS (2004) The American process of selecting a president: a comparative perspective. Pres Stud Q 34:632–655CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Spitzer AB (1983) Restoration political theory and the debate over the law of the double vote. J Mod History 55:54–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Young HP (1994) Equity in theory and practice. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2021

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Toulouse School of Economics, INRAUniversity of Toulouse CapitoleToulouseFrance
  2. 2.Toulouse School of Economics, CNRSUniversity of Toulouse CapitoleToulouseFrance
  3. 3.Institut Universitaire de France and Toulouse School of EconomicsUniversity of Toulouse CapitoleToulouseFrance
  4. 4.Ecole Normale Supérieure, Department of MathematicsUniversity of Yaounde IYaoundeCameroon

Personalised recommendations